E-books and e-publishing by Samuel Vaknin (essential reading .TXT) 📕
- Author: Samuel Vaknin
- Performer: -
Book online «E-books and e-publishing by Samuel Vaknin (essential reading .TXT) 📕». Author Samuel Vaknin
information available to them is either (a) insufficient or
(b) overwhelming. People will buy a book if the author’s Web
site provides only a few tantalizing excerpts. But they are
equally likely to buy the book if its entire full text content
is available online and overwhelms them. Packaged and indexed
information carries a premium over the same information in
bulk. Consumer willingness to pay for content seems to decline
if the amount of content provided falls between these two
extremes. They feel sated and the need to acquire further
information vanishes. Additionally, free content must really
be free. People resent having to pay for free content, even if
the currency is their personal data.
(5) Frills and bonuses. There seems to be a weak, albeit
positive link between willingness to pay for content and
“members only” or “buyers only” frills, free add-ons, bonuses,
and free maintenance. Free subscriptions, discount vouchers
for additional products, volume discounts, add-on, or
“piggyback” products - all seem to encourage sales.
Qualitative free content is often perceived by consumers to be
a BONUS - hence its enhancing effect on sales.
(6) Credibility. The credibility and positive track record of
both content creator and vendor are crucial factors. This is
where testimonials and reviews come in. But their effect is
particularly strong if the potential consumer finds himself in
agreement with them. In other words, the motivating effect of
a testimonial or a review is amplified when the customer can
actually browse the content and form his or her own opinion.
Free content encourages a latent dialog between the potential
consumer and actual consumers (through their reviews and
testimonials).
(7) Money back warranties or guarantees. These are really
forms of free content. The consumer is safe in the knowledge
that he can always return the already consumed content and get
his money back. In other words, it is the consumer who decides
whether to transform the content from free to paid by not
exercising the money back guarantee.
(8) Relative pricing. Information available on the Web is
assumed to be inherently inferior and consumers expect pricing
to reflect this “fact”. Free content is perceived to be even
more shoddy. The coupling of free (“cheap”, “gimcrack”)
content with paid content serves to enhance the RELATIVE VALUE
of the paid content (and the price people are willing to pay
for it). It is like pairing a medium height person with a
midget - the former would look taller by comparison.
(9) Price rigidity. Free content reduces the price elasticity
of paid content. Normally, the cheaper the content - the more
it sells. But the availability of free content alters this
simple function. Paid content cannot be too cheap or it will
come to resemble the free alternative (“shoddy”, “dubious”).
But free content is also a substitute (however partial and
imperfect) to paid content. Thus, paid content cannot be
priced too high - or people will prefer the free alternative.
Free content, in other words, limits both the downside and the
upside of the price of paid content.
There are many other factors which determine the interaction
of free and paid content. Culture plays an important role as
do the law and technology. But as long as the field is not
subject to a research agenda the best we can do is observe,
collate - and guess.
This article is, of course, free content…:o))
Copyright Law and Free Online Scholarship
An Interview with Peter Suber
By: Sam Vaknin
Also published by United Press International (UPI)
The battle between owners of content and its users extends to
all corners of the publishing world. Following a brief period
of enthusing about “synergies”, most media companies, content
aggregators, content providers - movie and recording studios,
publishers, news organizations - came to view the digitization
of content as a threat rather than an opportunity. In an
effort to protect their intellectual property rights,
publishing and recording corporations have fostered the
radicalization of copyright law (mainly in the DMCA - the
Digital Millennium Copyright Act). They have also retarded the
fair use of copyrighted material and the rights and
traditional privileges enjoyed by content users. This was
achieved mainly by incorporating “rights management” or “asset
management” technologies into readers of digital records (such
as e-books). These technologies prevented users from copying
the files they purchased, from converting them to audio, from
lending them to others (as they would a print book), and from
reading them on more than one device.
Consider, for instance, scholarly publishing. It is in the
throes of a protracted crisis.
The price of scholarly, peer-reviewed journals has skyrocketed
in the last three decades, often way out of the limited means
of libraries, universities, individual scientists and
scholars. A “scholarly divide” has opened between the haves
(the negligible minority of academic institutions with rich
endowments and well-heeled corporations) and the haves not
(all the others). Paradoxically, due to rising costs, access
to authoritative and authenticated knowledge has declined as
the number of professional journals has proliferated. This is
not to mention the long (and often crucial) delays in
publishing research results and the shoddy work of many under-paid and over-worked peer reviewers.
The Internet was suppose to change all that. Originally, a
computer network for the exchange of (restricted and open)
research results among scientists and academics in
participating institutions - it was supposed to provide
instant publishing, instant access, and instant gratification.
It has delivered only partially. Preprints of academic papers
are often placed online by their eager authors and subjected
to peer scrutiny. But this haphazard publishing cottage
industry did nothing to dethrone the print incumbents and
their avaricious pricing.
Peter Suber has both a Ph.D. in philosophy and a J.D. He is a
professor of philosophy at Earlham College, where he also
teaches law and computer science. This qualifies him uniquely
to tackle the issue of free online scholarship, which cannot
be divorced from the legal intricacies of copyright law. In
the last 11 months, he has been writing and publishing the
weekly the Free Online Scholarship (FOS) Newsletter.
Apart from writing the FOS Newsletter, Suber is working to
realize FOS on several fronts. He is a consultant to the Open
Society Institute on FOS issues. He is the general editor of
the Web’s foremost philosophy search engine Hippias and co-editor of Noesis, both available online free of charge. He
serves on the Committee on Philosophy and Computers of the
American Philosophical Association. He is on the board of
governors of the International Consortium for the Advancement
of Academic Publishing. With Tony Beavers, He is working on
software to collect, index, and search the literature at
distributed online journal sites and text archives.
Q: In “Revolt of the Poor”, I wrote: “If the rights to
intellectual property were not defined and enforced,
commercial entrepreneurs would not have taken on the risks
associated with publishing books, recording records, and
preparing multimedia products. As a result, creative people
will have suffered because they will have found no way to make
their works accessible to the public. Ultimately, it is the
public which pays the price of piracy.” Is there any proven
connection between the enforcement (or even the existence) of
intellectual property rights - and the preponderance of
creativity and/or of media entrepreneurship (publishing,
etc.)?
A: I don’t have the relevant expertise to answer for music,
software, general literature, or even scholarly books. But
for scholarly journal articles (the main focus of the FOS
movement), there seems to be very little or no connection
between copyright and the productivity and creativity of
authors. I say this for two reasons. First, scholarly
authors tend to transfer copyright in their articles to the
journals that publish them. (Most scholars don’t realize that
they could probably negotiate a different arrangement, but
that’s another issue.) For most journal articles, then,
copyright protects publishers, not authors. But this hasn’t
stopped scholars from writing journal articles. Second,
authors of scholarly journal articles are not paid for them,
whether they transfer copyright or not. Authors consent to
this practice and willingly submit their articles to journals
that don’t pay for submissions. Scholarly authors are paid by
their institutions, not by readers, which frees them from the
market in deciding what to write. They are rewarded by making
a contribution to knowledge and advancing their own careers,
not by cash. Hence, the “unauthorized copying” prohibited by
copyright law doesn’t deprive these authors of money, but only
readers. Copyright law (at least when used in the traditional
way to restrict access to paying customers) gets in the way.
Widespread copying with or without permission would give
authors of journal articles more readers and more impact,
without depriving them of any revenue. But copyright law
generally prohibits this kind of copying. Even though this
limit on free distribution is contrary to their interests, it
clearly hasn’t deterred authors from writing more articles.
Having said that, let me add that the FOS movement doesn’t
need to abolish or even reform copyright law. If authors of
scholarly journal articles retain the copyright to their
articles (transferring only, say, the right of first print
publication, and perhaps some other rights), then authors can
consent to widespread copying and finally let copyright
advance their interests rather than those of publishers. In
particular, authors could consent to put their writings on the
internet without any financial, legal, or technical barriers
to access. This is what the FOS movement is trying to
achieve, and it can all happen within the boundaries of
existing copyright law.
Q: Could you describe the crisis in scholarly publishing?
A: The main problem is that the prices of journals (both print
and online journals) have risen faster than inflation and
faster than library budgets for three decades. Libraries cope
by canceling subscriptions, or by taking from their book
budgets to enlarge their serials (journal) budgets, or both.
One result is that even researchers at the wealthiest
institutions do not have access to all the journals they need
for their research. Or, from the other end of the author-reader relationship, authors of journal articles cannot reach
all the readers who would benefit from the results of their
research. When research is slowed and obstructed in this way,
so are all the benefits of research, such as new medicines.
Another way to put the underlying economic problem is that the
huge savings that can be achieved by publishing to the
internet haven’t yet done anything to bring down the costs of
scholarly journals. One reason is that most journals still
have print editions whose costs are unaffected by the internet
revolution. Another reason is that the online editions of
most journals use expensive software to permit access to
paying subscribers and block access to everyone else. The
internet is only a revolutionary medium of nearly costless
dissemination for those who don’t manage subscription lists
and don’t try to distinguish between authorized and
unauthorized readers.
There are other dimensions to the scholarly publishing
crisis. One is that journal publishers (like software
publishers) are moving beyond copyright law to licensing
contracts give them even more protection. Publishers don’t
let libraries “buy” or “own” copies of electronic journals,
but only “license” them. As a result, libraries aren’t
assured that they have long-term access rights to these
journals, they have diminished rights to lend their copies,
and their patrons have diminished fair-use rights. They are
getting much less and paying much more.
If there were no alternative, that would be one thing. But
there is an alternative to the near monopoly concentration in
the scholarly publishing industry. There is an alternative to
harsh licensing contracts. And above all, the internet gives
us an alternative method of dissemination that widens
distribution and lowers cost at the same time. Even if there
were no crisis, the opportunity afforded by the internet would
be too beautiful to ignore.
Comments (0)